The Right Believes It Has the Supreme Court Votes to Entirely Overturn Labor Law
The foundational 1935 labor law protecting workers is unconstitutional, according to major corporations and right-wing zealots who believe they have enough votes on the Supreme Court to overturn it. In the latest sign that anti-union forces will doggedly press the matter, a federal judge for the Northern District of Texas enjoined the National Labor Relations Board (NLRB) from processing any allegations of employer violations of workers’ rights. The National Review hailed the decision as “A Welcome Blow to the NLRB.”
This is after Elon Musk’s SpaceX won a similar injunction against the NLRB before the Western District of Texas in July. Both cases will work their way up to the Fifth Circuit Court, which has served as an expressway to steer anti-regulatory legal appeals to the Supreme Court ever since Trump packed it with right-wing ideologues.
The arguments that the employers utilize, and even the immediate outcomes of these cases, are almost irrelevant to the ultimate goal: The right wing aims to repeal the 20th Century.
But, in trying to repeal all the rights and protections workers gained during the New Deal, including the limited protections that workers currently enjoy for organizing and engaging in collective bargaining, killing the 1935 National Labor Relations Act (also known as the Wagner Act) would also mean the lifting of a host of restrictions on unions’ ability to carry out solidarity activism and effective economic sanctions.
Are unions prepared for a return to “the law of the jungle?”
Here’s what the bosses in these cases are arguing: The National Labor Relations Board is unconstitutional because its staff — the administrative law judges (ALJ’s) who are tasked with investigating and litigating violations of the Act — were improperly appointed.
Basically, ALJ’s are hired by the National Labor Relations Board itself, a five-member body established by the act. Board members are nominated by the president and confirmed by the Senate, and serve staggered terms so that the board’s 3–2 partisan majority lags behind but eventually lines up with the party in power in the White House. As such, the argument goes, the ALJ’s are too removed from public accountability to be fair judges.
This was the logic that the Supreme Court applied to the Securities and Exchange Commission in last term’s SEC v Jaresky, which hobbled the power of the agency’s administrative law judges to levy fines. So, in some respects, the high court is already inviting a challenge to all similarly structured federal agencies, including the NLRB. But the Court’s first inclination may be to chip away at the labor board’s power, while the activist Right will keep trying to seize the opportunity to nullify the existence of the country’s main enforcer of workers’ rights.
University of Minnesota law professor Charlotte Garden doesn’t see any of the current Texas cases resulting in the total nullification of the NLRB. “What’s more likely,” she says, if the Supreme Court agrees with the Jarkesy argument, “is that the Court severs the good-cause provisions of the statute,” allowing ALJ’s and even Board members to be fired for any reason. “That’s what passes for optimism these days,” she ruefully adds.
Severing one part of the law deemed to be unconstitutional while allowing the rest of the act to remain on the books is exactly how the Supreme Court handled last term’s challenge to the Wagner Act, Starbucks Corp. v. McKinney. In that case, the Court “merely” diluted the NLRB’s power to seek speedy injunctions in cases of egregious union-busting during union election campaigns. The bosses won that case in an 8-to-1 vote, with Justices Elena Kagan and Sonia Sotomayor going along with the majority — showing that judicial hostility to unions extends to many Democratic appointees, potentially making nullification of the right to organize an easier lift than overturning the right to abortion.
Most employers raising these challenges aren’t out to change the law of the land but are “motivated by their usual desire for delay tactics,” Garden explains. Win or lose, delays – including the litigation of violations of the act – leave up to 43% of newly certified unions still fighting for a first contract after two years, according to one recent study.
Whatever employers’ immediate goals, these tactics have knock-on effects. Starbucks, which has an evolving labor peace deal with Workers United, the union that’s organizing its employees, stresses on its website that it is not joining SpaceX in challenging the constitutionality of the NLRB. But actions that Starbucks set in motion during its union-busting campaign still threaten the heart of labor law. In a September 18 hearing before the Third Circuit Court of Appeals in Philadelphia, Republican judges peppered Starbucks attorneys with questions about Jaresky in a case in which the company is fighting NLRB-ordered financial reimbursements for retaliatory terminations against union activists.
And throughout the country, the National Right To Work Foundation is “challenging the constitutionality of the NLRB with free legal representation” for scab Starbucks workers who were previously encouraged by their employer to fight the union.
Between all of these challenges, it’s likely that one or more circuit courts will rule the NLRB either partially or totally unconstitutional within the next six months, potentially putting an appeal on the Supreme Court docket as soon as October 2025. Regardless of the outcome, it’s clear that the forces of reaction are lining up case after case, and the arguments really don’t matter. They have their 6–3 majority on the Supreme Court, and they’re insisting that their bought-and-paid-for politicians in black robes vote as they are told.
Are unions preparing to lose both the protections – and the shackles – of the NLRB?
Two years into Ronald Reagan’s assault on workers’ rights, AFL-CIO President Lane Kirkland mused that labor might be “better off with the law of the jungle” if the NLRB was simply scrapped instead of having its mission twisted by movement conservatives.
“We’re the only exception to industry craving deregulation,” he said. “Let us go mano a mano. I think we could organize very rapidly.”
Kirkland was no radical militant, but his bluff was obliquely referring to a host of union protest tactics – from boycotts and partial or intermittent strikes to sit-down strikes and sabotage – that had been surrendered in exchange for government protections of the right to collective bargaining.
Before 1935, fights for union recognition often were pitched battles. Employers used spies, blacklists and armed Pinkertons. Unions fought back with mass picket lines and boycotts, and often destruction of property. Bosses usually prevailed because they had more guns and deeper pockets.
The National Labor Relations Act domesticated labor relations. It committed the federal government to protecting and encouraging the practice of collective bargaining, legally compelling employers to recognize and bargain “in good faith” with representative unions. The law protects workers from being fired or blacklisted for joining, organizing or voting for a union. It also prevents bosses from forming company unions or bribing union leaders. Employer violations are known as unfair labor practices, or ULP’s. The federal agency tasked with policing the law, the NLRB, is relatively toothless but can gain enforcement powers by taking recalcitrant employers to court (which is how the SpaceX and Starbucks cases got into court and on the way to the Supreme Court in the first place).
Unions accepted this framework. Many, if not most, employers eventually accepted it as well, especially as soon as the NLRB and the courts used the framework to remove the protections of the law from some of the labor movement’s most effective tactics. Most famously, and early on, the Supreme Court removed protections for workers who engaged in sit-down strikes in 1939’s NLRB v. Fansteel. Unions complied by dropping sit-down strikes from their arsenal, largely because the remaining protections of the law were still advantageous to making huge organizing gains. Union density grew from 11.5% before the Wagner Act was passed to 34.2% by 1945.
But employers, through their favorite politicians and judges, continued to constrict the range of protected union tactics. The 1947 Taft-Hartley amendment to the Act severely restricted unions’ ability to engage in solidarity activism (dryly called “secondary activity” in the law), such as boycotts of an anti-union company.
Imagine unionized grocery store workers refusing to uncrate boxes of Oreo cookies made at non-union factories, or Teamsters refusing to deliver Budweiser beer to non-union hotels. The power of solidarity can be enormous, which is why they made solidarity boycotts illegal (under the law they’re now trying to overturn).
But, if no union activity is protected because the NLRB ceases to exist, then all union tactics are potentially valid, or at least morally defensible, as long as unions are ready to fight back proportionally.
“I don’t think a lot of labor folks are focused on this right now,” says Stephen Lerner, a fellow at Georgetown University’s Kalmanovitz Initiative for Labor and the Working Poor, and an architect of Bargaining for the Common Good. “Unions are more focused on defeating Trump in the election, and on their current organizing and bargaining fights.” Regardless of the outcome of the election, Lerner says, “This is the culmination of a 50-year anti-union agenda and they’re going for it precisely at the moment that the labor movement is popular and on the move.”
To fight back against the right-wing assault and thrive in this era, Lerner says, “We should be prepared to revive the tactics that built union power in the first place.” Garden agrees, saying that without the NLRB, unions could “focus on what is strategically the best call, and not just what is protected.”
Seven years ago, I outlined a number of union activities that are, or should be, protected by the constitutional rights of free speech, due process, equal protection and even the Thirteenth Amendment’s ban on “involuntary servitude,” but were instead traded away by the regulatory approach of the NLRB. At the time, “Labor’s Bill of Rights” was an argument to engage in a campaign of judicial activism to reverse bad NLRB decisions. If the Supreme Court nullifies the NLRB, it should be added to the list of actions that unions should undertake in the aftermath.
Unions are most likely to respond to a federal reversal on labor law by trying to pass copycat Wagner Acts in pro-union states like California, Minnesota and New York. That’s not a terrible strategy, but framers of the new laws should take a “clean slate” approach to their lawmaking, taking the opportunity to strip deference to bad past precedents in case law, restoring any concerted worker protest activity to protection from employer retaliation, and streamlining state agency processes to ensure speed and prioritization of disputes in new union organizing cases.
Although the 1932 Norris-La Guardia Act, which prohibits federal judges from enjoining union picket lines, would remain on the books, making it — on paper, at least — the primary federal policy statement on private sector labor relations, we would see wide divergences between red and blue states in the treatment of union organizing.
However unions respond, Stephen Lerner cautions that time is of the essence. “Whatever we do that’s effective, if it’s not already illegal, they’ll rush to make it illegal.” Lerner points to UAW President Sean Fain’s proposal to line up 2028 contract expirations and align union bargaining demands with community and political demands in a general strike as the kind of planning that should be taking place now.
Assuming that the Supreme Court sticks to its cowardly practice of dumping its most unpopular decisions in the last week of the term in which it hears arguments, we have 20 months until the NLRB is shut down. In some ways, that is a luxurious amount of lead time for unions, which are capable of a tremendous amount of coordination. But debate and discussion need to begin now, not one year from now when the Supreme Court majority tips its hand during oral arguments. The right wing could not be clearer about their intentions. We must be ready.
[This article originally appeared at In These Times.]
Misjudging Labor
On June 13 the Supreme Court once again sided with a multibillion-dollar corporation over its workers. The case of Starbucks Corp. v. McKinney concerns seven employees, now known as the Memphis Seven, whom Starbucks fired in February 2022 as they tried to unionize their store in Tennessee. (Because federal law prohibits employers from retaliating against organizing, the company naturally claims they were let go for violating workplace policies.) The National Labor Relations Board (NLRB), the agency tasked with guaranteeing workers’ rights to join unions and negotiate contracts, was quick to intervene. Directed by the Biden-appointed General Counsel Jennifer Abruzzo, NLRB staff filed for a preliminary injunction to force Starbucks to reinstate the fired activists while the case was fully litigated.
Such requests are rare. The NLRB only makes them when companies glaringly violate labor law and the agency is confident that courts will decide the case in the workers’ favor. In August 2022 a lower-court judge agreed and granted the injunction.
That six-month wait for a modicum of justice was blazing speed by the standards of United States labor law. It was too fast for the Supreme Court, which, in an 8-1 decision, reversed the injunction. The justices ruled that when courts consider the NLRB’s injunction requests, rather than using a legal standard specific to labor disputes that gives the board relative deference, they must use a more restrictive standard known as “the traditional four-factor test,” as articulated in the 2008 case Winter v. Natural Resources Defense Council, Inc. Among the factors considered are the “balance of equities” (meaning that the ruling is fair to both sides) and that an injunction serves the “public interest.” Both factors are a matter of opinion. Put simply, the Court is placing its own views over the expertise of the NLRB’s professional staff, in the name of a “traditional” test that’s as old as a teenager.
The NLRB still needs to decide the case, which might take a year or more. A majority of its members—the Democrats—will likely agree that Starbucks violated the plain language of the law forbidding “discrimination in regard to hire or tenure of employment or any term or condition of employment to encourage or discourage membership in any labor organization.” When the agency returns to court for an enforcement order, the judges should rule in its favor once more, though Starbucks can appeal that decision as well.
All this delay favors employers. Union representation cases are usually won or lost in the years it takes to finish adjudicating a wrongful termination charge—the fired Starbucks workers included five of the six members of the organizing committee. Many cases are settled for cash payouts and a mutual agreement to call the matter a “resignation.” Sometimes unions trade settlements to get a company to withdraw its own charges or bargain in good faith. Starbucks is apparently negotiating under just such a brokered framework with the union, Workers United.
In one sense the consequences of Starbucks v. McKinney are relatively minor. Many Republican-leaning circuit courts were already using the four-factor test. In her partial dissent, Ketanji Brown Jackson agreed that it was the appropriate rubric but argued that it should be applied in a way that recognizes the NLRB’s authority, and that courts shouldn’t fully relitigate such cases: an “injunction request simply does not present the district court with an opportunity to wade into the midst of an ongoing labor dispute (over which it otherwise has no say) and offer its own take about how the merits should be decided.”
But in another, deeper sense, the Starbucks decision is a dispiriting sign that the courts will only allow labor rights to be revised downwards. The National Labor Relations Act, which Congress passed in 1935 to protect workers’ right to form unions and bargain collectively, may no longer be adequate to that task in a court system that has been historically pro-corporate but is especially conservative today in the aftermath of the Trump administration (though even two of the liberals, Elena Kagan and Sonia Sotomayor, joined the Starbucks majority). In another blow to unions, on June 28 the Court, in a more nakedly partisan 6-2 vote, eviscerated the forty-year-old Chevron deference, rejecting the subject-matter expertise and statutory interpretation not just of the NLRB but of all federal regulatory agencies. How might union supporters hoping to curb inequality wrest control back from the legal system?
*
Judicial hostility to labor is hardly a new phenomenon. As Jackson noted in her partial dissent, “To put it bluntly, courts exercising their equitable discretion amidst labor disputes today do so against the backdrop of an ignominious history of abuse.” In his classic study, Law and the Shaping of the American Labor Movement, the historian William E. Forbath showed how, in the nineteenth century, “judge made law”—that is, legislating from the bench—forced unions to adopt an essentially conservative political strategy.
In an era-defining decision in the case Lochner v. New York (1905), the Court overturned a New York law limiting working hours in bakeries, arguing that the legislation interfered with the freedom to contract under the due process clause of the Fourteenth Amendment.
As a result, in its early decades the American Federation of Labor (AFL)—the country’s largest labor organization—focused narrowly on contractual negotiations and largely gave up on state intervention as a solution to working people’s problems, except to try to prevent courts from intervening in labor disputes. When Roosevelt’s 1933 National Industrial Recovery Act tentatively endorsed collective bargaining and the right to organize, the Supreme Court overturned it using the Lochner doctrine. New York senator Robert Wagner then responded with the 1935 NLRA. That law stripped the courts of nearly all jurisdiction on cases pertaining to labor relations—essentially telling judges to keep their opinions on the subject to themselves—and created the NLRB, a parallel system of civil tribunals, which hears cases of alleged violations of workers’ rights to organize unions and go on strike. If the NLRB finds that an employer broke the law and cannot get them to comply or settle, it then and only then turns to the courts for enforcement (including injunctions). The NLRA was intended to supersede common law.
Set beside the original mandate of the NLRB, the Court’s decision in Starbucks v. McKinney couldn’t be more wrong. But the federal agency’s authority has eroded over time. In Values and Assumptions in American Labor Law, the legal scholar James B. Atleson narrated how, after the passage of the NLRA, the class biases of patrician judges led them to push back against pro-worker laws. “The belief in the inherent rights of property and the need for capital mobility, for instance, underlie certain rules,” Atleson writes, “and some decisions turn on the received superior need for continued production or the fear of employee irresponsibility.”
More recently, in his book The Supreme Court on Unions (2016), Julius B. Getman described how, if anything, the highest court’s historical antagonism to labor has only gotten worse in the last four decades. “What has remained constant over the years has been judicial arrogance,” he writes: “the willingness of the Court to establish factual premises for its decisions with little basis in reality.”
Take the right to strike, which is both specifically enumerated under the NLRA and clearly identified as one of its policy goals: “Nothing in this Act shall be construed so as either to interfere with or impede or diminish in any way the right to strike.” But this was undone just three years later in NLRB v. Mackay Radio & Telegraph Co., a 1938 case concerning the firing of striking workers at a regional telecom firm. Justice Owen Roberts upheld strikes as protected activity, but he also made a careless aside in his decision, musing that an employer would be allowed to permanently replace his striking workers if it was necessary “to protect and continue his business.”
In the following decades, employers pressed the outer edges of Mackay: Can we offer replacement workers super-seniority protection from layoffs while strikers are not similarly protected? (No.) How about give them vacation pay that strike participants are denied? (Also no.) By the 1980s, however, their efforts turned Justice Roberts’s offhand comment into stare decisis, a disastrous precedent that held that replacing strikers and only offering them their jobs back when scabs retire is “proper under Mackay.”
Judges also watered down the “balance of equities” protections, which were once robust enough to protect even the worst employees from retaliatory firings for union activism. Consider Walter Weigand, the subject of the landmark 1943 case Edward G. Budd Mfg. Co. v. NLRB. “If ever a workman deserved summary discharge it was he,” concluded a bemused circuit court judge. “He was under the influence of liquor while on duty. He came to work when he chose and he left the plant and his shift as he pleased.” If I’m not misinterpreting the court’s demure transcript, Weigand also ran a prostitution operation in the employer’s back alley (on company time) and testified that he had no idea what his actual job entailed. But he was only fired after switching from the boss’ company union to the more militant CIO, and for that reason the NLRB and the courts ordered him back on the job as the law intended.
But since 1980, the NLRB has applied what’s called the “Wright Line” standard for judging “mixed motive” terminations of union activists. It requires that a union prove that a worker was fired while engaged in protected union activity, that the employer knew the worker was a union activist, and that the employer held animus against the union. These demands in turn require more time-consuming litigation, even when an employer’s actions—like Starbucks firing people for talking to reporters about their union activism—wouldn’t pass a common-sense smell test. It’s not surprising, then, that the Wright Line standard has become a go-to union-busting weapon for employers. These days union supporters are fired in the course of nearly one in three certification votes brought before the NLRB.
*
An implicit assumption of the 1935 NLRA was that employers would remain neutral about organizing campaigns, and recognize a union if a clear majority of workers wanted one. But soon the Supreme Court had granted employers a First Amendment right to campaign against unionization and force employees to attend mandatory captive audience presentations. In the 1950s the NLRB fought for unions’ right to respond to these presentations, or at least mandate some access to the workplace, but since 1956 the Supreme Court has consistently supported employer’s property interests over unions’ access and speech.
What do employers say in captive audience meetings? In 1969 Chief Justice Earl Warren allowed them to threaten that a successful union drive would lead to workplace closures or other negative effects, as long as these threats were presented as predictions “carefully phrased on the basis of objective fact to convey an employer’s belief.” In a 2009 report, the labor scholar Kate Bronfenbrenner found that between 1999 and 2003, employers threatened plant closure in 57 percent of NLRB elections, and in 15 percent of the cases they actually followed through.
In all, it took the courts roughly thirty years to take workers out of a legal environment where union organizing was a fully enforceable right—with meaningful job protections and enforcement against threats, reprisals and the refusal to negotiate—to one where certification elections are conducted under manifestly crooked rules.
While corporations aggressively worked the courts, the AFL-CIO and its think-tanks pressed for legislative reform whenever the Democrats briefly controlled the White House and both chambers of Congress. But the Democrats only pursued narrow, technical fixes: a push to ban permanent replacements under Clinton; simple proof of majority, or “card check,” certification under Obama. Even these were vigorously resisted by the business lobby and eventually killed by filibusters. Biden’s is the first Democratic administration to meaningfully use the rules in place, and the NLRB’s rule-making authority, to encourage the practice of collective bargaining.
“Of all of the members of Biden’s administration,” the Nation has gushed, it’s Abruzzo “who has brought about the most significant changes for American workers.” Under Abruzzo the NLRB has sped up the timeline for conducting union representation elections. It has also expanded the instances in which employers must accept card check certification, has tried to limit the ability of employers to conduct mandatory captive audience meetings, and stretched for “make whole” financial penalties against employers who violate their workers’ rights. Even its decision to request an injunction in the Starbucks case was part of Abruzzo’s systemwide attempt to modernize operations. (The NLRB has not yet, I’ll note in case Abruzzo is reading, restored the right to strike by revisiting the Mackay standard and forcing employers to prove that they would go out of business if not allowed to hire permanent replacements.)
And yet any of these actions can be overturned if the Supreme Court finds they violate a precedent or employers’ First or Fourteenth Amendment rights. All of them, ultimately, cry out for new lawmaking. Restoring the promise of US labor law requires amending the NLRA to override unfair court precedent and reassert the NLRB’s supremacy over judges on routine enforcement of labor violations.
*
It is axiomatic on the left that lawmakers do not pass such prolabor legislation until a strike wave forces them to. Yet the historical record suggests otherwise. The “right” to organize was shoehorned into the National Industrial Recovery Act—the objectively pro-business “First New Deal” legislation that the Supreme Court overturned—to gain the AFL’s support for a controversial bill. It wasn’t won through workplace action, and lacking enforcement powers, it wasn’t worth the paper it was written on. But by offering just enough to raise workers’ expectations—and more to dash their hopes—it inadvertently birthed the very militancy needed to enshrine more meaningful reform.
This argument about the effect of the NIRA is still controversial. The labor activist and scholar Eric Blanc recently cut through decades of mythmaking and crunched the numbers. He found a 129 percent increase in union membership and a 260 percent increase in workers going on strike in the months that followed the act’s enactment. In my forthcoming book, We Always Had a Union: New York’s Hotel Workers Unions, 1912-1953, I show that the National Recovery Administration’s wage and hours code, in addition to failing to compel union recognition and reinstate fired union activists, directly caused a citywide hotel strike that the agency was attempting to mediate in January 1934. Though the unions didn’t “win” that strike, shaken hotel bosses negotiated a neutrality agreement so that the industry wouldn’t be hit with another work stoppage during the 1939 World’s Fair. The agreement resulted in the New York Hotel Trades Council, the union that remains a powerhouse in the city and state.
One lesson from this history is that unions need to be quicker to take advantage of favorable organizing environments. Today there is both a noticeable uptick of worker-led organizing (as evidenced by independent union wins at Amazon and Trader Joe’s, and wildcat job actions during the pandemic) and a pro-worker NLRB. And yet most unions are building up their savings accounts instead of spending down on new campaigns. Unions have collectively reduced their staff and organizers by an estimated 19 percent between 2010 and 2020, which translates to 23,440 fewer people that could potentially be put in the field. With the benefit of new leadership, the Teamsters and UAW are notable exceptions, joining a small handful of organizing champions like SEIU and UNITE HERE in investing significant resources on campaigns aimed at growing the labor movement, at huge employers like Volkswagen, Marriott hotels, and FedEx.
The other lesson is that opportunities for legal reform come rarely, briefly, and usually by surprise. There is no shortage of reform proposals like the PRO Act and the Clean Slate program. But too little attention is paid to counteracting judicial bias. If the Roberts Court’s judicial power grab, already a constitutional crisis, is to be met with more political brinkmanship like court-packing and Congressional overrides of politically motivated decisions, then why not center that fight on issues where judges’ historic tendency to favor corporations over workers cast them as perfect villains? Union supporters should be demanding that judges stop imposing their values and assumptions on accredited bodies like the NLRB. As the Transport Workers Union president Michael J. Quill once said of the man who sentenced him to jail for the 1966 New York City transit strike, “The judge can drop dead in his black robes.”
[This article originally appeared at New York Review of Books.]
Independent Unions Can Help Break Through the Economic Crisis and Labor’s Paralysis
In a period of extreme social and economic crises, when the major labor unions have reduced their organizing programs to a fraction of what they once were and the courts stand athwart any effort to protect workers’ interests, scrappy new independent unions raise hope against hope that maybe — just maybe — workers can fight back and win. I’m writing, of course, about the early 1930s. A newly published book finds some surprising parallels between that era and our own.
An eleventh volume in the prolific Marxist labor historian Philip S. Foner’s History of the Labor Movement in the United States has just been published, after it was discovered that Foner had completed the manuscript before he died in 1994. Subtitled The Great Depression 1929–1932, the book covers a period in which the established unions of the American Federation of Labor were not conducting many organizing campaigns or strikes and had little idea how to successfully contest for power in the large mass production industries that played a dominant role in American life.
As such, it’s really more of a history of the Trade Union Unity League (TUUL), the short-lived federation of independent labor unions sponsored by the Communist Party in the years before the emergence of the Congress of Industrial Organizations (CIO).
The TUUL has been maligned by many historians as a sectarian boondoggle that isolated the Communists from the early development of the CIO. Foner portrays the formation of the TUUL as a “necessary and unavoidable” response to the wholesale expulsion of Communist activists from the AFL’s mineworkers and garment workers unions as well as a sincere effort to organize new unions in industries that the AFL had no serious plans to take on.
Foner documents a revived Auto Workers Union, as well as a Steel and Metal Workers Industrial Union, that organized shop committees and published consciousness-raising shop papers during the long years that the AFL was still thinking of assembly line work as dozens of discrete crafts. Also chronicled are lesser-known unions like the Food Workers Industrial Union, which staged a strike in 1933 that successfully raised wages for 1,400 mostly black women who worked as nut pickers in St. Louis, and an Alabama Sharecroppers Union that defied violent racist repression.
Other heroic campaigns are highlighted, like the National Miners Union’s 1931 strike in “Bloody” Harlan County, Kentucky, which kicked off a decade-long struggle for union recognition, and Ben Gold and Fur Workers organizers facing down violent racketeers, gaining the loyalty of much of the rank and file, and leading eventually to collective bargaining and a CIO charter.
Foner was not particularly critical of the TUUL. He was a Communist, and in the last three volumes of his series, which coincide with the existence of the Communist Party, his analysis became much more partisan. That’s a shame, because it will cause some scholars and activists to continue to dismiss or ignore the lessons of this brief project of forming new, “pure,” left-wing unions outside the established labor movement. More recent scholarship has shown that the TUUL was more complicated, and more influential, than its critics have claimed.
Edward P. Johanningsmeier has shown that the shift from the 1920s strategy of “boring from within” the established unions (basically, the “rank-and-file strategy” of its day) to forming new unions was driven by organizers’ frustrations with the dirty tactics of trade union bureaucrats as much if not more than by “orders from Moscow.” Victor G. Devinatz has argued that the better measure of the TUUL’s legacy was not its membership numbers (which were pathetically low, perhaps never more than fifty thousand) but in the hundreds of thousands of workers who followed its leaders out on strike during these years, serving as a proving ground for organizers and giving workers some experience for the actual strike wave that would follow in 1934.
And Ahmed White has shown that former TUUL members, many of whom took jobs in the steel mills in order to organize a union, were the most dedicated activists during the long and sometimes violent SWOC organizing campaign at the “Little Steel” firms.
Foner’s is still, somehow, the first book-length treatment of the TUUL, and it’s well worth a read by activists who are currently, or thinking about, forming new independent unions. The surprise NLRB election victories of the Amazon Labor Union in Staten Island and the Trader Joe’s Union in Hadley, Massachusetts, have provoked serious debate over the efficacy of organizing without the resources and expertise (and baggage and bureaucracy) of traditional labor unions.
My takeaway: it’s hard to blame workers for organizing independently of unions that won’t seriously commit resources to unionizing the industries they claim jurisdiction over. But most independent unions (historically speaking) have not amounted to much on their own. Where the TUUL unions were able to inspire workers to protest their working conditions, though, they left a road map of workplaces for the CIO to concentrate on a few years later. And where TUUL leaders inspired rank-and-file confidence in their strategies, they were sometimes able to negotiate their way into AFL and CIO unions to score the resources necessary to win when collective bargaining became legally protected.
A History of the History
It’s a strange delight to hold a “new” volume of Foner’s History of the Labor Movement in one’s hands, its cover the same red and blue gear, with the same typeface and International Publishers logo on the spine, three decades since the series was presumed to have ended with Foner’s life. (Amalgamated Transit Union organizing director Chris Townsend learned of its existence and fought for its publication, and SUNY Empire State College professor emeritus Roger Keeran got the manuscript into publishable form.)
A massive work across over four thousand pages, Foner published the first volume in 1947. He conceived the series as a Marxist rebuttal to the then-dominant Wisconsin school of labor history, which treated the broad sweep of labor’s story as an evolutionary process that resulted in the ideal policies and practices for unions: those of the American Federation of Labor in the 1920s (which, in retrospect, was a historical nadir of union membership, organizing activity, and political power for labor).
Foner’s approach was institutionalist (making heavy use of minutes and official journals to document organizations), but his focus was more on strikes and organizing campaigns, making the theme of his series the conflicts that are the whole point of having a labor movement.
The books are arranged thematically (earlier volumes include The Industrial Workers of the World 1905–1917 and The Policies and Practices of the American Federation of Labor 1900–1909) and chronologically, which I’ve found makes them a go-to reference when researching any particular event in order to get a sense of what else was going on in the labor movement at the time.
Foner’s choice to focus just on the first four years of the Great Depression is instructive. The historical memory of the New Deal tends to get smushed together, causing a lot of fuzzy thinking on the Left of the interplay between labor militancy and legal reform. In fact, radical changes were occurring on a year-to-year basis before Franklin D. Roosevelt even took office. (Rutgers labor studies professor Eric Blanc has been working through this in the series of working papers he put out this summer, “Labor Struggle from Below and Above: Lessons from the 1930s.”)
Aside from the TUUL, Foner highlights the unemployment demonstrations of the first years of the crisis and the AFL’s long, tortured internal disagreements about pushing for a system of unemployment insurance (which the federation had derided since the days of Samuel Gompers) as a “dole” that would make workers subservient to the government. As we have seen during our own COVID-19 crisis, workers are more likely to risk protesting on the job when they have some kind of safety net to fall back on.
The most important reform during these years was the anti-injunction Norris-LaGuardia Act, still the most important labor law in this country. Prior to the legislation, employers routinely made workers sign “yellow dog” contracts promising not to join a union. When unions went on strike, employers would go to federal court — yellow dog contracts in hand — and argue that the picket lines were interfering with their contract rights (as well as their property right to expect their employees to come to work every day). The courts would just as routinely issue injunctions, and the National Guard would violently shut the strikes down.
The Norris-LaGuardia Act made it the federal government’s stated policy to encourage the “full freedom of association, self-organization, and designation of representatives . . . free from the interference, restraint, or coercion of employers.” More practically, it outlawed yellow dog contracts and basically forbade federal courts from issuing injunctions that restrained workers’ strike and picket line activity.
That this great law was written by two Republicans (albeit liberal ones, when that was still a thing) and signed by a Republican president is illuminating. By the early 1930s, enough senators were so frustrated by the court’s pretzel logic on property rights, its conservative legislating from the bench, and its dithered views on Congress’s power to regulate interstate commerce that they actually voted down one of Herbert Hoover’s Supreme Court nominees and passed the Norris-LaGuardia Act by a veto-proof majority.
Would that we had enough senators of either party today who would vote to strengthen labor law as a “fuck you” to the Roberts Court.
Had Foner lived long enough to complete the History of the Labor Movement in the United States (a sisyphean task for any one scholar), the twelfth volume would probably have dealt with Roosevelt’s “first” New Deal, the industrial code-setting National Recovery Administration with its Section 7a “right” to organize — a gift lobbed toward a feeble labor movement to buy just a little opposition to a controversial bill — that, in turn, triggered the 1934 strike wave. And the thirteenth volume would likely have covered the advent of the National Labor Relations Board, the sit-down strikes, and the period that we tend to think of as “labor’s great upsurge” (and, again, tend to romantically misremember as occurring earlier in the New Deal timeline).
Perhaps now, a quarter of a century since Foner’s passing, the time is right for a new generation of scholars to pick up his mantle.
[This article originally appeared in Jacobin.]
15 Years Ago, Mad Men Quietly Began Its Engagement With Leftist Ideas
The prestige drama Mad Men, which ran for seven seasons, beginning fifteen years ago this month, received plenty of awards and close readings from mainstream critics. The Left press largely slept on it, which is a shame: the series was not only very funny and poignant and offered viewers a lot to chew on about the changing politics and gender roles of the 1960s, but seemed to draw direct inspiration from socialist thought. Series creator Matthew Weiner tipped his hand that Mad Men would at least play with Marxist critiques of capitalism in the very first episode with two simple words: “It’s toasted.”
That advertising slogan is prominently featured in a classic mid-century Marxist text, Monopoly Capital: An Essay on the American Economic and Social Order by Paul A. Baran and Paul M. Sweezy. In an age when supermarket shelves were newly and fully stocked with competing technicolor boxes of breakfast cereal and the constant introduction of “new” and “improved” products, the two writers, associated with the Marxist magazine and book publisher Monthly Review, argued that “competition, which was the predominant form of market relations,” had been replaced by “large-scale enterprise producing a significant share of the output of an industry, or even several industries, and able to control its prices, the volume of production, and the types and amounts of its investments.”
Monopoly, in other words, wasn’t an occasional mistake of the capitalist system — now it was the system.
One of Baran and Sweezy’s central arguments is that the massive surplus value (or, more crudely, the profits) generated by monopoly capital could be democratically and equitably distributed to provide for the material needs of all members of society. Instead, it’s wasted.
One particularly egregious form of waste they target is the commercial advertising business, which was rapidly expanding in the 1960s. Instead of reinvesting surplus in innovation or using the lowered costs of production to make more products available to more people, advertising wastes vast fortunes on convincing consumers that one identical product is somehow superior to another.
In the process of advancing this argument, Baran and Sweezy cite a bit of Madison Avenue braggadocio from ad exec and author Rosser Reeves: the George Washington Hill tobacco company’s “It’s toasted” advertising campaign — “So, indeed, is every other cigarette, but no manufacturer has been shrewd enough to see the enormous possibility of such a simple story.”
The plot of Mad Men’s first episode centers on an impending Surgeon General report that will link smoking tobacco to lung cancer. This is a crisis for the series’ protagonist, Don Draper.
Not a health crisis, of course. In fact, Draper, the head of the creative department at the fictional Sterling Cooper advertising agency, is first introduced smoking a cigarette and sketching out tobacco ad campaigns on the back of a cocktail napkin in preparation for a high-stakes meeting with his largest client, a tobacco company. Cigarette advertising had long emphasized the supposed therapeutic benefits of smoking, and the client wants a plan for how to continue selling a product when the public inevitably finds out it’s deadly.
To prove his point, Draper asks the men to describe how their cigarettes are made. His client, the patriarch of Lucky Strike, blathers on about insect-repellent seeds, the North Carolina sunshine, and the harvesting, curing, and toasting of the tobacco leaves.
“There you go!” Draper declares about the fact that tobacco leaves are toasted before they’re rolled into cancer sticks. When the owner’s son objects that all cigarette tobacco is toasted as part of the manufacturing process, the advertising agency’s head of creative counters, “No. Everybody else’s tobacco is poisonous. Lucky Strike’s is toasted.”
This was not a famous advertising campaign. It’s hardly “Where’s the Beef?” and was for a completely different cigarette maker. It seems clear that Matthew Weiner read Monopoly Capital and drew some inspiration from it. But what, if anything, was he trying to say about the advanced stage of capitalism and artistic creativity in an industry built on lies and deception?
A Beautiful Sentiment
Early reviewers noticed that Mad Men was slyly feminist, with secretary-turned-copywriter Peggy Olson’s slow climb toward professional respect and artistic ambition marking her as the show’s parallel (if not primary) protagonist. From early on, interviewers drew out Weiner on the influence that Betty Friedan’s Feminine Mystique and Helen Gurley Brown’s Sex and the Single Girl had on his pilot script.
Those were bestselling books. But Cold War–era Marxist economic texts are deeper cuts, so Monthly Review’s contribution to Mad Men has gone unremarked upon.
Baran and Sweezy are not the last or even the most obvious example of Mad Men cribbing from leftist texts. A third-season episode has a pair of copywriters, recently hired to help court the emerging baby boomer market, making a “kids these days” presentation about developing a youth market for a client, a coffee brand, to Draper.
The smarmier of the two, Smitty, launches into an already passé staccato faux-beatnik rap about “this letter from a friend back in Michigan . . . he’s still in school, man, and it’s got this — I dunno — sixty-page rant in it.” He reads from it: “We would replace power rooted in possession, privilege, or circumstance by power and uniqueness rooted in love, reflectiveness, reason, and creativity.”
Though unnamed in the episode, that “rant” is the Port Huron Statement, the founding document of Students for a Democratic Society and a seminal text of the New Left.
“That’s a beautiful sentiment,” Draper replies sardonically. “Does your friend know what you do for a living?”
Smitty replies with a slightly deflated, “Yeah . . . there was a shitty note with it.”
How quickly and eagerly young men would seek to commodify youth rebellion to sell instant coffee is treated as a bitter joke. There is some creativity required to repackage anti-capitalist sentiment as a new and improved lifestyle that can be purchased at the supermarket. But that creative spark is wasted on cynical exploitation.
A major theme across Mad Men’s seven seasons is the tension between the creative talent at an advertising firm and the accounts executives who keep the corporate clients happy (and the revenue flowing). At one point in the series, Draper bellyaches that the creative department is the “most important, least important thing there is.” The most important element in advertising, of course, is actually the buying and selling of radio and television airtime and column inches in newspapers and magazines (in its 1960’s business model, at least). That’s where the money is made. But the creatives are essential for selling the lie that one cigarette is superior to another (and that they will all kill you should not be a primary concern).
In its first three seasons, the idea of advertising as “selling out” creative ambition is most fully represented in the character Paul Kinsey, a senior copywriter who fashions himself as a bohemian and wears his admiration for Rod Serling and Orson Welles on his sleeve (and his bearded face). He lets anyone who will listen know that he’s always writing something that could turn into the Great American Novel, or at least an episode of The Twilight Zone. We also see him try to blow up a pitch meeting with the Pennsylvania Railroad Company to protest the demolition of its classic train station in 1963, as well as participate in — and chicken out during — the Mississippi Freedom Rides that summer.
Advertising as Art
Draper, in the early seasons, is similarly drawn toward the bohemian Greenwich Village, and stays on top of the latest novels and movies. One imagines he could create greater art than hokey tag lines for Life cereal. Peggy similarly winds up in the orbit of artists who can at least score an invite to Andy Warhol’s Factory.
Even the accounts men have a creative drive. Senior partner Roger Sterling spends the fourth-season year of 1965 writing his (poorly received) memoir, Sterling’s Gold, and an early episode in season one has the announcement that junior accounts executive Ken Cosgrove published a short story in the Atlantic, stirring jealousy among the other young men in the office.
With Cosgrove out of earshot, Kinsey and Peter Campbell and Harry Crane confess their artistic pretensions and cook up plans to get their own abandoned (and seemingly sophomoric) stories published; Campbell going so far as pressuring his wife, Trudy, to reconnect with an ex-boyfriend in the publishing business. Cosgrove, we find out, continues to pseudonymously publish genre short stories even as his accounts responsibilities increase — causing “fellow frustrated writer” Sterling (perhaps in a fit of jealousy) to forbid him from continuing to do so as a senior executive.
Whatever Matthew Weiner had to say about the employment of creative talent in a wasteful and unnecessary industry, it seems he intended to give the audience two potential interpretations in the series’ ambiguous final scene. Having walked out of the stultifying environment of the enormous McCann Erickson advertising agency after it absorbed and dissolved the small firm that Draper dedicated years of his life to building up, Draper dries out and meditates at a California hilltop yoga camp with an ambiguous smile on his face. Before the scene cuts to black, it fades in a soundtrack and visuals from a vastly more famous advertisement than “It’s toasted.”
The real-world McCann Erickson managed to turn a jingle for Coca-Cola, “I’d Like to Teach the World to Sing,” into a chart-topping single in 1971 on the strength of a stunningly cynical ad that featured vaguely multicultural hippies embracing on a hilltop. Sure, the ad sought to reassure its audience, you just saw cops beat the shit out of those idealistic Students for a Democratic Society kids in Chicago and now a bunch of them are blowing up federal buildings to protest the whole system, and your new president was elected through a strategy of racist “law and order” dog-whistling. But at least Coke brings us all together.
If you rewind and slow-mo the moments before Draper’s Mona Lisa smile, you’ll notice hairstyles and outfits from the Coke ad surround him as workers and guests at his newfound hilltop hippie camp. Is he smiling because this scene that he’s stumbled upon has inspired him to innovate a new decade of exploiting baby boomer culture to sell a national culture back to them in the form of diabetes in a bottle? Or is the dark joke of Mad Men that, even when an advertising creative walks away from a lucrative career of emotional manipulation and lies, the machine keeps on humming without him?
The problem is that as much as Matthew Weiner leaned on the famous cut-to-black ending of The Sopranos (his artistic home when he was writing Mad Men’s pilot) as a sort of “choose your own mythology,” his recent interviews have placed a heavy thumb on the scale in favor of the interpretation where Draper returns to New York to pitch the hippie Coke ad. Why does the internet tempt creators to ruin their endings by commenting on them? Weiner had ample opportunity to put a more definitive version on the screen and didn’t. What now privileges his head canon over my own, where Draper remains retired and returns to New York to be a present father for his kids and a reliable friend to the handful of female colleagues he managed to avoid sleeping with?
The ending in Weiner’s head is one of the most disappointingly cynical statements that a TV show that began with a nod to how advertising contributes nothing of productive value to society could have landed upon. It suggests a triumph of capitalism so complete that not only is making emotionally manipulative advertising an art that artists should settle for because the system makes room for it, but that it is the kind of creatively fulfilling work that an artist should aspire to. I’d rather stay at yoga camp.
[This article originally appeared in Jacobin.]